How long can today’s record-low, major currency interest rates persist? Ten-year interest rates in the US, the UK and Germany have all been hovering around the once unthinkable 1.5 per cent mark.

It is nonsense to argue that Central Banks are unable to raise inflation expectations- Kenneth Rogoff

In Japan, the 10-year rate has drifted to below 0.8 per cent. Global investors are apparently willing to accept these extraordinarily low rates, even though they do not appear to compensate for expected inflation. Indeed, the rate on inflation-adjusted US Treasury bills (so-called TIPS) is now negative up to 15 years.

Is this extraordinary situation stable? In the very near term, certainly. Indeed, interest rates could still fall further. Over the longer term, however, this situation is definitely not stable.

Three major factors underlie today’s low yields. There is the “global savings glut”, an idea popularised by current Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke in 2005. Savers have become ascendant across many regions. In Germany and Japan, aging populations need to save for retirement. In China, the government holds safe bonds as a hedge against a future banking crisis and as a by product of efforts to stabilise the exchange rate.

Similar motives dictate reserve accumulation in other emerging markets. Finally, oil exporters such as Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates seek to set aside wealth during the boom years.

Second, in their efforts to combat the financial crisis, the major Central Banks have all brought down very short-term policy interest rates to close to zero, with no clear exit in sight.

In normal times, any effort by a Central Bank to take short-term interest rates too low for too long will boomerang. Short-term market interest rates will fall, but, as investors begin to recognise the ultimate inflationary consequences of very loose monetary policy, longer-term interest rates will rise.

This has not yet happened, as Central Banks have been careful to repeat their mantra of low long-term inflation. That has been sufficient to convince markets that any stimulus will be withdrawn before significant inflationary forces gather.

But a third factor has become manifest recently. Investors are increasingly wary of a global financial meltdown, most likely emanating from Europe, but with the US fiscal cliff, political instability in the Middle East, and a slowdown in China all coming into play. Meltdown fears, even if remote, directly raise the premium that savers are willing to pay for bonds that they perceive as the most reliable, much as the premium for gold rises. These fears are also restraining business investment, which has remained muted, despite extremely low interest rates for many companies.

It is the combination of all three of these factors that has created a “perfect storm” for super low interest rates. But how long can the storm last? Although highly unpredictable, it is easy to imagine how the process could be reversed.

For starters, the same forces that led to an upward shift in the global savings curve will soon enough begin operating in the other direction. Japan, for example, is starting to experience a huge retirement bulge, implying a sharp reduction in savings as the elderly start to draw down lifetime reserves.

Japan’s past predilection towards saving has long implied a large trade and current-account surplus, but now these surpluses are starting to swing the other way.

Germany will soon be in the same situation. Meanwhile, new energy-extraction technologies, combined with a softer trajectory for global growth, are having a marked impact on commodity prices, cutting deeply into the surpluses of commodity exporters from Argentina to Saudi Arabia.

Second, many (if not necessarily all) Central Banks will eventually figure out how to generate higher inflation expectations. They will be driven to tolerate higher inflation as a means of forcing investors into real assets, to accelerate deleveraging, and as a mechanism for facilitating downward adjustment in real wages and home prices.

It is nonsense to argue that Central Banks are impotent and completely unable to raise inflation expectations, no matter how hard they try. In the extreme, governments can appoint Central Bank leaders who have a long-standing record of stating a tolerance for moderate inflation – an exact parallel to the idea of appointing “conservative” central bankers as a means of combating high inflation.

Third, eventually the clouds over Europe will be resolved, though this does not seem likely to happen soon. Things will likely get worse before they get better, and it is not at all difficult to imagine a profound restructuring of the eurozone. Whichever direction the euro crisis takes, its ultimate resolution will end the extreme existential uncertainty that clouds the outlook today.

© Project Syndicate, 2012, www.project-syndicate.org.

Kenneth Rogoff, a former chief economist of the IMF, is Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Harvard University.

Sign up to our free newsletters

Get the best updates straight to your inbox:
Please select at least one mailing list.

You can unsubscribe at any time by clicking the link in the footer of our emails. We use Mailchimp as our marketing platform. By subscribing, you acknowledge that your information will be transferred to Mailchimp for processing.